home *** CD-ROM | disk | FTP | other *** search
- history
- farm subsidies: a necessary evil?
-
- Subsidies are payments, economic concessions, or privileges given by the
- government to favor businesses or consumers. In the 1930s, subsidies were designed to
- favor agriculture. John Steinbeck expressed his dislike of the farm subsidy system of
- the United States in his book, The Grapes of Wrath. In that book, the government gave
- money to farms so that they would grow and sell a certain amount of crops. As a result,
- Steinbeck argued, many people starved unnecessarily. Steinbeck examined farm subsidies
- from a personal level, showing how they hurt the common man. Subsidies have a variety
- of other problems, both on the micro and macro level, that should not be ignored. Despite
- their benefits, farm subsidies are an inefficient and dysfunctional part of our economic
- system.
- The problems of the American farmer arose in the 1920s, and various methods
- were introduced to help solve them. The United States still disagrees on how to solve
- the continuing problem of agricultural overproduction. In 1916, the number of people living
- on farms was at its maximum at 32,530,000. Most of these farms were relatively small
- (Reische 51). Technological advances in the 1920's brought a variety of effects. The
- use of machinery increased productivity while reducing the need for as many farm laborers.
- The industrial boom of the 1920s drew many workers off the farm and into the cities.
- Machinery, while increasing productivity, was very expensive. Demand for food, though,
- stayed relatively constant (Long 85). As a result of this, food prices went down. The
- small farmer was no longer able to compete, lacking the capital to buy productive
- machinery. Small farms lost their practicality, and many farmers were forced to
- consolidate to compete. Fewer, larger farms resulted (Reische 51). During the
- Depression, unemployment grew while income shrank. "An extended drought had
- aggravated the farm problem during the 1930s (Reische 52)." Congress, to counter this,
- passed price support legislation to assure a profit to the farmers. The Soil Conservation
- and Domestic Allotment Act of 1936 allowed the government to limit acreage use for
- certain soil-depleting crops. The Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 allowed
- the government to set the minimum price and amount sold of a good at the market. The
- Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1938, farmers were given price supports for not growing
- crops. These allowed farmers to mechanize, which was necessary because of the scarcity
- of farm labor during World War II (Reische 52). During World War II, demand for food
- increased, and farmers enjoyed a period of general prosperity (Reische 52). In 1965, the
- government reduced surplus by getting farmers to set aside land for soil conservation
- (Blanpied 121). The Agricultural Act of 1970 gave direct payments to farmers to set
- aside some of their land (Patterson 129). The 1973 farm bill lowered aid to farmers by
- lowering the target income for price supports. The 1970s were good years for farmers.
- Wheat and corn prices tripled, land prices doubled, and farm exports outstripped imports
- by twenty-four billion dollars (Long 88). Under the Carter administration, farm support
- was minimized. Competition from foreign markets, like Argentina, lowered prices and
- incomes (Long 88). Ronald Reagan wanted to wean the farm community from
- government support. Later on in his administration, though, he started the Payments In
- Kind policy, in which the government paid farmers not to grow major crops. Despite
- these various efforts, farms continue to deal with the problems that rose in the 1920s.
- Farm subsidies seem to have benefits for the small farmer. "Each year since
- 1947, there has been a net out-migration of farm people (Reische 53)." American farm
- production has tripled since 1910 while employment has fallen eighty percent (Long 82).
- Small family farms have the lowest total family incomes (Long 83). Farming is following
- a trend from many small farms to a few large farms. Competition among farmers has
- increased supply faster than demand. New seed varieties, better pest control, productive
- machinery, public investments in irrigation and transportation, and better management
- will increase farm output. The resulting oversupply of farm products, which creates a low
- profit margin, drives smaller farms out of business. Smaller farms lack the capital and
- income to buy the machinery they need to compete with larger farms (Long 85). Many
- see this tendency towards consolidation and mechanization of farms to be harmful to the
- United States in the long run, and they see subsidies as a way of achieving a social
- desire to preserve the family farm. "If the family farm represents anything, it's a very
- intimate and fundamental relationship between people and resources (MacFadyen 138)." Fewer
- farms mean fewer jobs and a higher concentration of wealth. Ten 30,000-acre farms may
- produce as much food as a hundred 3000-acre farms, but the former supports machinery;
- the latter, community (MacFadyen 138). Farm subsidies are designed to prevent the
- extinction of the small farmer.
- Despite the social benefits, subsidies have many problems. The subsidy system
- is often wasteful; the government finances irrigation systems in the California Imperial
- Valley, and then pays farmers not to grow crops on it (Solkoff 27). Some benefits hurt
- the small farmer. Marketing orders and tax breaks hurt small operators by giving more
- money to bigger farms. Big farms can then overproduce and undersell using advanced
- machinery, driving lesser farms out of business (Fox 28). Subsidies also allow foreign
- markets to become competitive by artificially raising market prices (Long 91). Artificially
- raising market prices create a surplus that would normally be solved by the free market
- system. In a theoretical free market, overproduction would drive excess farms out of
- business, until equilibrium would establish itself for both price and quantity of farm
- products. Subsidies allow inefficient farms to continue to exist, which creates an
- inefficient economic system. Subsidies also increase the cost of other consumer products,
- while also increasing taxes to pay for them. Perhaps most importantly, subsidies do not
- fulfill their social role. "About 112,000 large farms-- equivalent to the number of farms in
- Minnesota alone-- produce half the nation's food and fiber (Long 82)." The many
- government subsidy policies do not preserve the family farm, and the number of small
- farms has almost continuously been on the decline. Subsidies are impractical in the
- economic and the social aspects.
- Despite perceived benefits, farm subsidies are an inefficient and dysfunctional
- part of our economic system. Their goal, nonetheless, is noble. Writers like John Steinbeck
- made people aware of the plight of the small farmer, and subsidies were the only solution
- he government could think of. If there is some way to prevent the decline of small farms
- that does not carry the many subsidy problems, the agricultural policy would undoubtedly
- change. Perhaps the same anti-trust laws that prevented the monopolizing of industry
- could be used to prevent the consolidation of farms. Until some other system is developed
- that can deal with the problems of the farmer, subsidies will continue to be used.
-
- Works Cited
-
- Blanpied, Nancy. Farm Policy. Congressional Quarterly: Washington D.C., 1984.
- Fox, Michael. Agricide. Schoken Books: New York, 1986.
- Long, Robert Emmet. The Farm Crisis. Wilson Co.: New York, 1987.
- MacFadyen, J. Tevere. Gaining Ground. Holt, Reinhart, and Winston: New York, 1966.
- Reische, Diana. U.S. Agricultural Policy. Wilson Co.: New York, 1966.
- Solkoff, Joel. The Politics of Food. Sierra Club Books: San Francisco, 1985.
-